A billionaires’ tax is justified—and Elon Musk and Jeff Bezos are inspired by more than money

Let’s do a simple thought experiment. Assume that tonight we redistribute the country’s income and wealth so that everyone has the same amounts. That would have enormous consequences, including on wages and prices. Chauffeurs’ wages would go down; childcare workers’ wages might go up. Prices of beachfront properties in the Hamptons and on the Riviera would go down; prices of land elsewhere might go up.

Bernard Arnault and his family, owners of the luxury goods conglomerate LVMH (which owns a host of brands like Christian Dior and Moët Hennessy) and one of the richest families in the world, might not be so rich if there were not so much inequality. They have absolutely thrived on it. But if the distribution of dollars is the result of exploitation today or in the past—­as is the case—­then the prices and wages that emerge even in a competitive market lack moral legitimacy, even if the rules today were set in a morally legitimate way.

This should make clear that even in perfectly competitive markets the magnitude of the rewards may have no fundamental moral justification, even if there’s a strong moral or economic argument that people who work or save more should be rewarded for their hard work and willingness to save.

The case is even stronger after we come to understand the multiple distortions in the economy. No market economy even approximates a competitive ideal of perfect competition, perfect information, and perfect risk and capital markets. Each “failure” can have significant effects on prices and, therefore, on the opportunity sets of different people. And even small deviations from the perfections required by the competitive ideal have big consequences. This is one of the important implications of the information revolution in economics over the past forty years.

Freedom, moral claims, and redistribution

Consider an economy with large disparities in income and wealth. Should the government impose progressive taxes to fund public goods, like investments in basic research and infrastructure? I have argued that behind the veil of ignorance there would likely be consensus that the government should. Libertarians retort that everyone has a certain moral legitimacy to his own income, well deserved because of his hard work, intelligence, and thrift.

But think about what their incomes would have been had they been born in a poor country, without the rule of law or the institutions, infrastructure, and human capital that make the economies of advanced countries work so well. It is not enough to have assets such as entrepreneurial talents. If you are born into the wrong environment, those assets mean nothing. They yield the returns they do only because of the socioeconomic environment in which we live. And if that’s the case, we owe our income and the wealth that derives from it as much to that environment as to our own skills and effort. There is full justification, then, for imposing high taxes on high incomes even in a perfectly competitive economy in which wealth is garnered in ways that have full moral legitimacy.

Likewise, the moral claim against progressive taxes is slim if high incomes arise out of luck or inheritance—­and even more so if they are made possible through exploitation or because the rules that generate or allow such incomes have been shaped by access to political power. There is no presumption that the laws and regulations are themselves set in a fair way even in a competitive economy. Quite the contrary, with political power linked to economic power and economic power linked to the economic rules set in our political processes.

Trade-­offs in freedoms

In a society with a fixed amount of resources, expanding one person’s budget constraint—enhancing the freedom to spend—­necessarily constrains others’. Redistributive taxation, of course, does this. Libertarians focus on the restraints that taxation imposes on the rich rather than on the loosening of the constraints on the people living in poverty who will have more to spend because of the income transfers or who will be better able to live up to their potential because of the education or health benefits they receive.

The world, of course, is more complicated; it is not “zero sum.” Taxes, as actually imposed, may reduce work or savings, and therefore national output, because they reduce the return to work or savings. The provision of better education and health can expand output enormously. How large the effects are in each case is a subject of debate; the magnitude clearly influences assessments of trade-­offs.

Assessing the magnitude and nature of the trade-­offs is hard, and it is the subject of inquiry of many an economist. I am of the view that conservatives typically exaggerate the adverse consequences of progressive taxation.

Some of the wealth of the very rich is the result of luck. To the extent that it’s luck, redistribution and funding better social protection may increase economic output. The randomness of outcomes discourages work and investment. A good system of social protection may encourage people to undertake high-­risk, high-­return activities. Corporate-­profits taxation with loss offsets has long been seen as a form of risk-­sharing, with the government as a silent partner, and long been shown to increase risk-­taking and investment.

Some of the high profits are a result of skill, but often skill in exploiting others and creating market power. To the extent that effort is directed at rent-­seeking, we want to discourage it because it decreases GDP and increases inequality. Taxes on monopoly profits curb incentives to create market power and, together with rules curbing exploitation, redirect effort to more constructive activities.

But even when efforts at the very top are focused on socially desirable entrepreneurship, it’s hard to believe that higher taxes, especially on exorbitant corporate profits, will matter much. Do we really believe that Jeff Bezos, Bill Gates, and Elon Musk would not have accomplished what they have if they could take home only $30 billion rather than the massive amounts they do? These entrepreneurs may have been driven by money, but also by much more than that.

Excerpted from The Road to Freedom: Economics and the Good Society by Joseph E. Stiglitz. Copyright © 2024 by Joseph E. Stiglitz. Used with permission of the publisher, W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. All rights reserved.

W. W. Norton & Company

Subscribe to the CFO Daily newsletter to keep up with the trends, issues, and executives shaping corporate finance. Sign up for free.
Visited 2 times, 1 visit(s) today

Related Article

Meta擬斥資1560億元擴建AI雲端 攜手甲骨文加速算力佈局

AI狂潮下,英偉達、甲骨文及OpenAI近日宣布瘋狂大投資,Meta(META.US)也急起直追,拉攏甲骨文(ORCL.US)洽談一項金額達200億美元的AI雲端運算擴大合作方案。Meta執行長朱克伯格(Mark Zuckerberg)解釋,在人工智慧浪潮中「不夠積極」的風險遠高於「過於積極」的風險,並多次強調即使投入數千億美元,也絕不讓Meta在AI領域落後,並强調Meta「沒有倒閉的風險」。 路透社報導援引知情人士透露,Meta與甲骨文正就一項多年期新約進行深入洽談。該合作內容預計將由甲骨文提供大規模雲端運算基礎設施,以滿足Meta在訓練與推論AI模型所需的龐大運算資源。若此交易能順利達成,預估將為甲骨文帶來可觀的營收貢獻,並進一步鞏固其在AI雲端服務市場的地位。 消息傳出後,甲骨文股價周五(19日)收盤上漲4.06% 朱克伯格此前曾多次公開表示,即使投入數千億美元,也不願Meta在AI領域落後。他誓言將公司資源傾注於AI發展,目標是建立「超級智慧」(superintelligence)能力。 為實現這一宏大願景,Meta正大舉投資於AI基礎設施和人才招募。 朱克伯格近期在 Podcast 節目「Access」中進一步闡述,他正投入大量資金,以確保Meta不會錯過人工智慧的巨大機遇。他坦言,AI泡沫「很有可能」出現,並指出歷史上不乏企業因過度建設而倒閉,但卻留下寶貴資產的先例。然而對Meta而言,更大的風險在於猶豫不決。 朱克伯格表示:「如果我們最終浪費了數千億美元,我認為這顯然會非常不幸。但我想說的是,實際上另一邊的風險更高。」 他強調,如果一家公司發展速度過慢,而人工智慧的到來又比預期的早,那麼在「我認為將會是史上最重要的技術、能帶來最多新產品、創新和價值創造」的領域,就會處於劣勢。他補充道:「對於像Meta這樣的公司來說,風險可能在於不夠積極,而不是過於積極。」 朱克伯格也進一步指出,對於像Meta這樣的大公司,「我們沒有倒閉的風險」。但他提到,像OpenAI和Anthropic這樣的私人公司,則面臨著能否繼續融資的問題。他補充道,這不僅取決於它們的表現和人工智慧的發展軌跡,還取決於更廣泛的經濟狀況。 據悉,Meta在2025年的AI基礎設施資本支出預計將高達720億美元,這也是其至2028年6000億美元總體計畫的一部分。朱克伯格本月稍早表示,到2028年,Meta將在美國資料中心和基礎設施上投入至少6000億美元。財務長蘇珊李 (Susan Li) 隨後澄清說,這一數字涵蓋了Meta在美國所有數據中心的建設,以及「所有用於支持我們美國業務運營的投資」,包括新員工的招聘。這些投資將用於興建如「普羅米修斯」(Prometheus)和「海柏利昂」(Hyperion)等大型AI超級運算集群,以提供前所未有的算力支持。 Text by BusinessFocus Editorial 免責聲明:本網頁一切言論並不構成要約、招攬或邀請、誘使、任何不論種類或形式之申述或訂立任何建議及推薦,讀者務請運用個人獨立思考能力自行作出投資決定,如因相關言論招致損失,概與本公司無涉。投資涉及風險,證券價格可升可跌。

A letter to Dong Yaoqiong—China’s disappeared ‘ink girl’

  In the summer of 2018, a young woman splashed ink on a poster of Xi Jinping in Shanghai, sparking a tragic chain of events that have left at least two people dead and another disappeared, presumed dead. Dear Dong Yaoqiong, We’ve never met, but we have followed your tragic story and that of your

Bill Gates, RFK Jr. 'Agreed to Disagree' on Vaccines, Gates Says

By Jennifer Rigby NEW YORK (Reuters) -Philanthropist and Microsoft co-founder Bill Gates met once with U.S. Health Secretary Robert F. Kennedy Jr. since he took office, and the two “agreed to disagree” about vaccines, Gates told Reuters in an interview on Monday. Kennedy has long promoted doubts …

In a dizzying few days, Trump ramps up attacks on political opponents and 1st Amendment

WASHINGTON — President Trump has harnessed the weight of his office in recent days to accelerate a campaign of retribution against his perceived political enemies and attacks on 1st Amendment protections. In the last week alone, Trump replaced a U.S. attorney investigating two of his political adversaries with a loyalist and openly directed the attorney general to

Jonathan Bailey, Naomi Campbell and more celebrities

Burberry’s spring/summer 2026 show for London Fashion Week on Sept. 22 show brought out super stylish looks from Jonathan Bailey, Naomi Campbell, Rosie Huntington-Whiteley and more. Below, see what everyone wore. 1 of 24 Rosie Huntington-Whiteley Dave Benett/Getty Images for Burberry 2 of 24 Jonathan Bailey Alan Chapman/Dave Benett/Getty Images for Burberry 3 of 24

Wall Street Journal Seeks Dismissal Of Trump’s Defamation Lawsuit

The Wall Street Journal, its parent company and Rupert Murdoch asked a federal judge to dismiss Donald Trump‘s $10 billion defamation lawsuit over the publication’s report on the president’s past connections to Jeffrey Epstein. “In an affront to the First Amendment, the President of the United States brought this lawsuit to silence a newspaper for